IMAGINATION TOWARD A THRIVING SOCIETY
 

Turning Aces into Assets

Four Options to Help the Government Turn Its Addiction to Gambling Revenue into Assets for the Poor

Topics: Economics, Gambling

Executive Summary

Government-run gambling is ripe for reform. In our previous report, "Pressing Its Luck," we examined the ways in which the state’s gambling monopoly operates as a tax on the marginalized—preying on the poor and those who are playing hard to join them. We concluded by offering four policy reforms that could help provinces kick their addiction to regressive gambling profits and build a system that works for, not against, low-income households. Here, we provide a more detailed framework for recovery by exploring each policy option in depth. Returning annual gambling profits to the poor through cash transfers is one option. A second is to promote asset building through a matched savings program. Governments can also work with financial institutions to offer prize-linked savings products, an innovative way to help families build emergency savings funds. Finally, given that gambling profits are drawn disproportionately from problem gamblers, we argue that governments should increase funding for problem-gambling research, prevention, and treatment out of provincial gambling corporations’ marketing budgets.

Introduction

Governments have a gambling problem. Across Canada, provinces have become addicted to the cash that state-run gambling provides to their treasuries each year. But a government’s gambling monopoly is more than just a lucrative form of entertainment: it functions as a hidden and regressive tax on the poor and the addicted. If government will continue deriving revenues in this manner, how could this gambling money be put to better use? How might government build a gambling structure that empowers those on the economic margins, rather than preying on them? This paper explores policy options to put this money back in the hands of those whom government-run gambling harms most, and to ensure that the government’s use of these funds is open, transparent, and accountable.

We’ll bet you’re wondering where we get our numbers. Rest assured, we’re not stacking the deck. This paper is a sequel to our June 2020 report “Pressing Its Luck” and assumes readers are familiar with the background data and rationale presented in that report. We encourage you to read it at https://www.cardus.ca/research/work-economics/reports/pressing-its-luck/.

As noted in Cardus’s major study on provincial gambling policy in Canada,1 gambling profits are treated just like tax revenues. Yet there is a significant difference in the way that these two types of revenue sources are collected, and in the burden that they place on citizens. Income and sales taxes are carefully designed to ensure that the poor shoulder a lighter tax burden than those with more: the proportion of income collected in income taxes from the wealthiest quintile is nearly ten times higher than that collected from the poorest quintile, and low- to moderate-income taxpayers receive regular rebates from the government to prevent their being disproportionately affected by sales taxes. Gambling, however, is a regressive revenue source—that is, relative to income it taxes the poor more heavily than the rich. Households in Canada’s lowest income quintile spend an average of 5.7 percent of their income on gambling each year. This is nearly three times the rate paid by the country’s highest-quintile households (see Figures 1 and 2).2 Meanwhile, between 15 and 50 percent of gambling revenue comes from problem gamblers, even though they make up only 1–4 percent of the population (see Figure 7).3

For more information, see “Pressing Its Luck,” 12–23.

4

The best way for government to make amends is to take these funds and direct them toward policies aimed at addressing the savings gap: poorer Canadians have much more difficulty saving and building assets than do their middle- and upper-class counterparts, not only because they have lower incomes but also because government incentives to save are tailored to higher earners. The impetus for our project was to help make saving easier for people like Alice, whom we met (as readers may remember) during previous Cardus research on payday loans.

For more information, see “Banking on the Margins,” 19–20.

We learned that one of the factors that made Alice vulnerable was low levels of liquid savings in the bank, making an expensive and risky payday loan her only option when a financial emergency struck. “Alice” is not a single person but an acronym used by DFC Global Corporation, one of the world’s largest providers of payday loans, to describe its target customer: “asset-limited, income-constrained, employed.”5 This is the demographic—those who are financially vulnerable due to low incomes and few assets—that we have in mind when we say that our goal is to help the poor save.

For more information, see “Pressing Its Luck,” 24–25.

Provinces spend millions of dollars each year on gambling advertisements that urge players to spend their extra dollars rather than putting them away (see Figures 3 through 5). Lottery ads urge ticket buyers to dream of the financial freedom and security that winning might bring, a dream particularly tantalizing for those who feel locked out of traditional pathways to wealth. Polls have found that around a third of Canadians plan to fund their retirement with lottery winnings. Meanwhile, American data suggest that lower-income families are particularly likely to believe that hitting the jackpot is their best shot at wealth: nearly two-fifths (38 percent) of households with annual incomes below $25,000 said that winning the lottery was the most practical way for them to accumulate several hundred thousand dollars, while only 21 percent of the total sample said the same.6 Yet rather than fulfill these hopes, the gambling system siphons wealth from citizens’ bank accounts: governments make money from casinos and lotteries only because gamblers come out poorer in the long run.

Meanwhile, the families disproportionately harmed by the gambling system are the same families that benefit least from government policies designed to encourage saving. The federal government spends $45 billion on tax-advantaged registered savings plans such as RRSPs, which proportionately are used by and benefit middle- and upper-income Canadians with higher taxable incomes and who thus have more to gain from income-tax exemptions, deferrals, and deductions.7 Even TFSAs, which were meant to fill this savings-policy gap, remain underused by lower-income savers.8 The upshot is that those who could most use some extra help building savings are the least likely to get it. Restructuring Ontario’s gambling system to ensure that funds are used to incentivize savings for those on the economic margins would rectify the injustice inherent in our current system and further the prospects of Ontario’s poor.

Canada’s household savings rate has fallen dramatically over the last few decades.9 (The household saving rate spiked in 2020 as a result of government income-support programs and lockdown-related restrictions on spending,10 but whether high savings rates will continue as COVID-19 subsides is unclear.) Canadian families saved around 20 percent of their income in the 1980s compared to just 5 percent in 2018.11 In one 2019 survey, one-quarter of Canadians reported that they didn’t save anything at all in the past year.12 Meanwhile, household debt levels have soared from 85 percent of disposable income in the 1990s to 170 percent today.13 Canadian households’ debt service ratio—the proportion of disposable income spent on debt payments—is projected to rise.14

And it’s not just savings writ large that is a challenge. Short-term saving for financial emergencies is critical for families with lower incomes: “While a low savings rate can slow the economic progress of middle- and upper-income families, the absence of savings can prove disastrous for lower-income households. That is because one function of savings is as a cushion for emergencies, such as losing a job or to cover an automobile repair in order to get to work.”15 A lack of assets may put families at greater risk of falling into poverty in the future, even though their current incomes put them above the poverty line.16 Even a small amount of savings can reduce financial vulnerability significantly, especially for those who lack access to good credit.

The Urban Institute, for example, found that a buffer of just $250–$749 makes families less vulnerable to hardship in the face of income loss.17 After controlling for other characteristics, households with $500 or less in liquid savings in their bank accounts are 2.6 times more likely to use payday loans than households with $2,000 to $8,000 in the bank.18 Yet many Canadians are struggling to build up even a small buffer of emergency savings. In 2015, 29 percent of Canadians reported that their emergency savings would last a month or less. Almost half (44 percent) said that they had $5,000 or less in emergency savings. And 46 percent of Canadians said the lack of an emergency savings fund, either past or present, caused their debt to increase.19

The economic calamity induced by the COVID-19 pandemic has drawn fresh attention to the importance of a savings buffer. Sudden layoffs on an unprecedented scale have demonstrated that a loss of income can strike anyone at any time.20 Yet claims for unemployment benefits spiked into the millions at a time when close to half of working-age Canadians do not have enough financial assets to cover their basic living expenses for three months.21 Evidence from the United States suggests that savers have weathered the economic storm better than those without anything set aside: even after losing half of their pre-COVID income, families with savings were less likely to have to borrow, take on credit-card debt, or postpone bill payments to make ends meet compared to those whose incomes were similarly reduced but had no savings.22

Saving is an important way for households to build assets over the long term, improving financial stability and economic mobility. Research has found that the possession of assets has positive effects on individuals, families, and communities—such as increased confidence and higher rates of social and civic engagement—that are distinct from the effects of income. Assets have been linked to positive educational outcomes for children,23 and “children of low-income, high-saving parents are more likely to experience upward income mobility” compared to children of low-income, low-saving parents.24 Low-income families with savings have better financial resilience than middle-income families without savings.25 And apart from any long-term impact on net worth, the habit of saving may itself “provide a sense of accomplishment that counteracts feelings of financial distress,” a security separate from and in addition to the security that the income and savings themselves provide.26

Building financial security for all Canadians, but especially for the most vulnerable, is widely recognized as an important policy priority. With public budgets already upended by the pandemic, governments have a unique opportunity to kick their gambling addiction with relatively little disruption to provincial balance sheets. It’s time to reform the provinces’ gambling scheme to work for, not against, low-income households. But how? We examine four options below.

Option 1: Return gambling profits to the poor through cash transfers

The simplest option for policy-makers would be to give gambling money back to the poor. Instead of subsidizing general spending with a regressive tax taken from the pockets of the poor, the group disproportionately providing the tax would be the group that benefits from the tax. This policy would in many respects be no different from existing sales-tax rebate programs like the GST/HST tax credit: in order to prevent sales taxes from disproportionately burdening low- and moderate-income families, households whose incomes fall below a certain cut-off receive a quarterly payment from the government to offset the amount of sales tax they pay.27

For more information, see “Pressing Its Luck,” pg. 25-29.

Cash-transfer programs are a common policy tool for both federal and provincial governments. Canadian examples include the Canada Workers Benefit (successor to the Working Income Tax Benefit),28 Old Age Security29 and the Guaranteed Income Supplement,30 the Canada Child Benefit,31 and various provincial income-assistance programs. These can be paid out as a monthly income supplement (like the Guaranteed Income Supplement or Canada Child Benefit) or as an annual lump sum based on an individual’s income-tax return (like the Canada Workers Benefit). Most transfers are means-tested, with payments phasing out above a given income level. A new cash transfer funded by gambling profits—called, say, the Gaming Savings Credit (GSC)—could follow the same structure as existing transfers. Each year, a province’s total gambling profits would be divided among all households below a certain income cut-off, and the province would send a GSC cheque to each one. This benefit would be real money for low-income families: in Ontario, the GSC would have been worth around $1,886 per low-income adult in 2018; in Atlantic Canada, $1,888; in Alberta, $4,469; in British Columbia, $2,875.32 (It should be noted that these totals are similar to the amount of liquid savings in bank accounts linked to a significantly lower risk of using a payday loan.)

Policy benefits and disadvantages

The chief advantage of this policy option is its familiarity, which makes it easy to design and administer. Policy-makers could take advantage of existing infrastructure for determining eligibility for the benefit and delivering payments. The administration of the program would be particularly efficient if eligibility were tied to another transfer program—for instance, everyone receiving Ontario Works payments could be made eligible for the GSC. Another advantage to bundling the GSC with an existing program is that policy-makers would have flexibility in setting the parameters of the new transfer. If a government wanted to design the program to give a larger benefit to people with disabilities or to families with children, it could use the same sliding scale and supplements that have already been established in other programs: everyone who receives the disability supplement of the Canada Workers Benefit, for example, could receive a higher GSC payment.

3334

Researchers have studied cash transfers extensively and have found positive effects on the well-being of low-income families and on children in particular. Unconditional transfers have been linked to positive educational outcomes, especially for poorer children.35 There is modest evidence to suggest that unconditional cash transfers improve some health outcomes, increase the likelihood of enrolling in and attending school, and lead to higher spending on health care in low- and middle-income countries.36 In Canada, child benefits have grown increasingly effective at reducing low-income rates over the past two and a half decades, especially for women.37 Following the introduction of the Canada Child Benefit, food insecurity declined among Canadian families, with the effect most pronounced among financially vulnerable families.38 The Canada Child Benefit has been associated with better maternal health as well as improved test scores and mental health for children.39 Low-income pregnant women receiving an unconditional cash benefit in Manitoba had better birth outcomes than their comparable counterparts who did not receive the benefit, resulting in a narrower outcomes gap between high-income women and low-income women receiving the benefit.40 When researchers examined how the benefit contributed to the improved outcomes, they found that the unconditional nature of the transfer was key to the program’s success: women “were empowered to choose how to use the benefit to best meet their needs.”41

42

Evidence from the Working Income Tax Benefit, Canada Child Benefit, and the Earned Income Tax Credit, an American transfer program, indicates that while most recipients spend at least a portion of their refund and benefit income immediately, much of the money is used for necessities such as food, housing, and school supplies.43 Jones, Milligan, and Stabile demonstrate that low-income families in Canada spend their Canada Child Benefit income on tuition and educational supplies and on household essentials, including child care, basic food in stores, and transportation. They also find evidence that receiving the Canada Child Benefit causes families to reorganize their budgets in financially healthy ways, observing decreases in spending on restaurant meals, alcohol, and tobacco.44 Similarly, Adams, Amedah, and Fougère examine the Canada Child Benefit and find that families use their benefit to pay for child care and school-related expenses.45

Yet the GSC also has its drawbacks. Perhaps the most problematic is a corruption of purpose—money is being taken from the same vulnerable groups that it is then used to support. Our response to such an argument would be that since gambling is here to stay, and the best place for the profits to go is to the government (rather than a corporation whose primary duty is to enrich shareholders rather than promote the common good, or even worse, organized crime), these profits should be used to benefit the people most harmed before any other group.

For more information, see “Pressing Its Luck,” pg. 20-21.

Another concern is that supplementing income assistance with gambling profits might simply mean a reallocation (i.e., a lowering) of other expenditures related to income support, leaving the government’s gambling addiction intact. The recent recommendation of creating a type of sovereign wealth fund with “sin taxes”46 is particularly vulnerable to this concern. If the government uses the GSC as an excuse to cut program costs elsewhere, the GSC will have done little more than move money around. It may even make the situation worse, by causing policy-makers to think that they have succeeded at solving the problem—or by strengthening the incentive to increase gambling revenues in order to support a good cause. In this case, the only potential success of the policy would be if GSC funds were kept separate from general revenues, which would increase transparency in the use of gambling money and thus improve government accountability.

As with other cash-transfer programs, the GSC could have negative labour-market effects if not carefully designed. The new means-tested benefit income could act as a disincentive to employment for households receiving it, particularly if this income is clawed back as earnings rise (or interacts with other transfer programs to have a similar effect).47 But this danger is not inherent in the transfer itself, simply a consideration for program design. Other cash-transfer programs such as the Working Income Tax Benefit / Canada Workers Benefit and the Earned Income Tax Credit were carefully—and, as research has demonstrated, fairly successfully—designed to encourage labour-market participation.48 One possible solution would be to tie eligibility for the GSC to receipt of existing transfer programs with work incentives. In addition to reducing potential labour-market barriers, bundling these credits would streamline the administrative process. Moreover, while the GSC would be large enough to have a meaningful positive impact on a low-income household’s finances, it is still a relatively modest sum at just under $2,000.

Even more relevant to the other goals of this paper, a transfer is not biased in favour of savings habits. Both Ottawa and the provinces already have a suite of transfer policies that provide income assistance to the poor, but as mentioned above, the existing policy framework does very little to help low-income Canadians save (and in many cases includes strong disincentives for saving, such as asset limits in means-tested programs). Those whose financial vulnerability stems from asset poverty rather than income poverty won’t be helped by another transfer program designed to boost income.49

The GSC could however be oriented toward saving by including in the program an incentive to save the benefit payment. Rather than issuing monthly cheques, the government could pay out a lump sum once a year so as to prevent dependence on these funds to pay bills. As a further nudge toward savings, the credit could be deposited directly into a recipient’s TFSA.50 Though this approach would involve some additional administrative work for those who had not yet set up a TFSA, this barrier would be relatively low since almost all Canadian adults have at least one account at a bank or other financial institution.51 Another way to deliver this payment would be to bundle it with a person’s annual income-tax refund. Low-income families could be encouraged to save some (or all) of their refund when they receive it. Indeed, many organizations working to build financial security have targeted tax time as a valuable window to incentivize saving by offering a matching credit to those who save some of their refund. Tax refunds are the largest single chunk of money many low-income households can expect to receive in a year. While they may not have much left over to save after paying the bills in a typical month, their refund gives them some extra cash that could be put away, placing them in a better position to handle a financial emergency if one strikes later in the year.52 Tax-time incentivized savings programs have met with moderate success in both Canada and the United States.53

As with the transfer program itself, there are both benefits and drawbacks to enhancing the GSC with a tax-time savings incentive. On the one hand, it would help meet the need for savings incentives targeted to income- and asset-poor Canadians, and it would be a relatively low-touch program compared to other matched savings initiatives (which we turn to next). But on the other hand, such a program would need to be administered in cooperation with community services organizations (to promote and explain the savings option, provide tax-filing assistance, and help interested participants deposit their benefit and withdraw their match a year later) and/or financial institutions (to deliver the savings accounts and monitor which account holders maintain their balance long enough to be eligible for a match). There are many non-profit organizations and financial institutions already doing this kind of work across Canada, so a government interested in exploring this option would have plenty of partners with whom it could initiate a tax-time saving-program trial. Nevertheless, the involvement of multiple players and the year-long timeline eliminate the very simplicity that might make this policy option more appealing than the others.

Conclusion

As with existing sales-tax rebate programs, returning gambling profits to low-income Canadians through a cash-transfer program like the GSC would help prevent governments from relying on a regressive revenue source that disproportionately burdens the poor. It could work with other transfer programs to improve the financial well-being of vulnerable households. Policy-makers would need to design the program carefully to ensure transparency and avoid unintended negative effects. While the GSC does not directly address the lack of savings incentives tailored to low-income households, there are nevertheless several options available to build savings nudges into the program in partnership with civil-society organizations.

Option 2: Promote asset building with matched savings

A second policy option is to use gambling profits to fund a matched savings program. At its most basic level, this program would use gambling dollars to reward saving by matching participants’ contributions to designated savings accounts. Many governments and non-profit organizations use a wide variety of matched savings programs to encourage saving. One of the most well-known Canadian examples is the Registered Education Savings Plan, a program in which the government adds money to a savings account designated for a child’s education. On the more intensive side are programs modelled after individual development accounts (IDAs), an asset-based welfare initiative developed by Michael Sherraden in his seminal 1991 book Assets and the Poor: A New American Welfare Policy.54 IDA programs generally have several common components. At their core is a savings account for low-income individuals, who can earn matching credits on every dollar they save up to a maximum or match cap. Eligibility is means-tested, restricted to those below a certain income threshold and holding a limited amount of liquid assets. Participants have a designated period of time in which to save toward a specific goal. During this time, they receive training—sometimes voluntary, sometimes mandatory—in financial management, such as budgeting skills and different types of credit. Participants receive matching credits with their deposits only if they use their withdrawals for designated investments, typically education or training, starting a small business, or homeownership.

IDAs and similar matched savings programs are designed to accomplish several interrelated objectives. They directly fill the gap in tax-based and other financial incentives for saving that low-income households experience. They are designed to help participants reach a financial goal that will improve their long-term earning potential and, ideally, net worth. The program is generally structured in such a way as “to kick-start a savings habit,”55 encouraging participants to save regularly during and after the program. The financial education and coaching help improve participants’ financial literacy. Tying the matching credits to a formal savings account also works to strengthen participants’ connection to mainstream financial institutions, which tends to be weaker among low-income households (whose lower levels of income, financial capital, and assets make accessing credit more difficult, since banks have less information and fewer indicators with which to evaluate their credit risk).56

Several developed countries have tested asset-building policies on a large scale in recent years. The American Dream Demonstration followed fourteen IDA programs, representing about 2,400 accounts across the country, from 1997 to 2002, and found that the poor can save: the average participant saved US$16 (CA$21) per month—nearly US$200 (over CA$250) per year—and the poorest participants saved a higher proportion of their income than others. IDAs are now offered by hundreds of social-service organizations across the United States.57 Another matched savings program is the United Kingdom’s Help to Save program (a successor to the extensively piloted, but ultimately axed, Saving Gateway).58 The program offers 50p for every £1 saved by eligible participants. Participants have four years in which to save and can earn up to £1,200 in matching bonuses on their savings.59 Eligibility for Help to Save is tied to eligibility for other means-tested credits.60 While asset limits for some (though not all) means-tested programs are sensitive to participants’ contributions to their Help to Save accounts (i.e., the amount of benefits participants receive will be affected if their own deposits exceed the asset limits of these programs), benefit payments are not affected by the bonuses paid through Help to Save.61

IDAs or similar matched savings accounts are also available in certain parts of Canada, where they are offered by non-profit organizations including SEED Winnipeg (Saving Circle,62 IDA,63 Inner City Homebuyer Program64), Momentum Calgary (Matched Savings for Youth, formerly Youth Fair Gains65; Matched Savings for Adults66; Savings Challenge67), Burnside Gorge Community Association (Family Self Sufficiency Program68), and Family Services of Greater Vancouver (Common Cents69), often in partnership with credit unions such as Vancity,70 Assiniboine,71 and Coast Capital Savings (see Figure 6).

The learn$ave demonstration project

By far the most significant IDA program in Canada was the learn$ave demonstration project, a matched savings pilot program that began in June 2000 and issued its final report in November 2010. In total, the project enrolled 4,802 low-income working adults, including 3,808 participants at three experimental sites set up as a randomized control trial.72 Applicants selected for the program at those sites were randomly sorted into one of three groups: learn$ave plus (who received matching savings credits plus financial-management training and case management), learn$ave only (who received matching savings credits without any additional training), or the control group (who received neither financial management training nor matching credits).73

Most features of the program followed the traditional IDA model closely. Participants opened their learn$ave accounts at partner financial institutions, which included one bank and several credit unions. All learn$ave participants (i.e., not the control group) received basic administrative support, but learn$ave-plus group received more intensive case management and financial-skills training.74 Both learn$ave-only and learn$ave-plus participants received three dollars in matching credits for every dollar they deposited and had three years to save.75 After the project ended, participants could convert their learn$ave accounts into a regular deposit account at the same institution.76

The demonstration showed that even those with relatively constrained finances can save. Most participants opened an account, saved in it (an average of $1,100 over three years), and used their matched credits.77 Based on learn$ave participants’ self reports, there was a small but statistically significant increase in the proportion of self-identified savers after the financial incentive expired. The program also helped participants save more regularly, with the combination of credits and services having a modest impact on regular saving. Program participants were more likely to report an intention to save in the future.78 Families did not give up essentials to max out their savings—participation in learn$ave did not lead to increased hardship.79 Nevertheless, there was a significant proportion of participants whose early saving behaviour indicated that they would likely have been able to save without learn$ave’s added incentives; there were also several participants who failed to use all their earned credits.80

Policy benefits and disadvantages

The matched savings policy option has the advantage of being highly customizable to the policy goals of various governments. Policy-makers would have the flexibility to determine the program’s match rate—for every dollar deposited by a low-income saver, government could contribute between, say, 50 cents (under a more modest program) and $3 (a more ambitious program)—and match cap. The program could be high-touch, with financial training and intensive case-management services offered to a select group of participants as featured in the conventional IDA model; alternatively, policy-makers could implement something more akin to Help to Save, offering a simple saving match to a broader group. Matching credits could be restricted to long-term investments such as buying a home, starting a small business, or enrolling in post-secondary education, or use of the credits could be unrestricted. Regardless of which model is used, the benefits are simple and easy for all users to understand—“anyone who saves $1 gets $2 from the government,”81 compared to, say, “depending on your annual income and family structure, you may be eligible for some or all of this new tax credit.”

Matched savings programs can help participants get into the habit of saving if they are designed with the right rules and incentives. Including monthly deposit requirements may help encourage regular and genuinely new saving rather than reallocation of assets.82 The income constraints experienced by poor households mean that policy-makers will have to design withdrawal rules carefully—restrictions should not be so strict that funds cannot be withdrawn if there is a real emergency, and there should be opportunities for both short- and medium-term savings.83 If the use of matched credits is restricted to certain purposes, there should still be some flexibility and the cash-out process should be made as easy as possible.84 An essential part of program setup is coordinating with different levels and departments of government on asset rules for means-tested programs so as to ensure that asset limits on income-assistance eligibility are not a disincentive to participate.85 It will be difficult to convince a low-income household to sign up for a matched savings program if they believe it could jeopardize their existing benefits.

In addition to the promising results of learn$ave, evidence from other matched savings programs suggests that these programs are effective for building savings habits. In one of the relatively few studies of IDA participants’ longer-term savings outcomes, Loibl et al. found that after controlling for other variables, IDA program completion was a significant predictor of household saving and had a long-term effect on asset accumulation after the program ended, leading the researchers to conclude that “successful IDA program completion may improve the financial dispositions and behaviors associated with long-term savings.”86 Another study of IDAs found that participants showed stronger habits of saving than comparable non-participants; this habit strength grew over time to peak at nineteen to twenty-four months, approximately the length of most IDA programs.87 American Dream Demonstration participants have also reported in qualitative interviews that the program helped them develop a saving habit.88 In the second Saving Gateway pilot, a large majority (71 percent) of account holders made net deposits in at least sixteen of the program’s eighteen months, and three in five (61 percent) saved enough to earn the maximum government match (two-thirds of whom continued to save even after reaching the limit).89

Even small-scale programs run by private non-profit organizations have experienced great success with matched savings programs. Participants in SEED Winnipeg’s Saving Circle experienced a statistically significant increase in money management and budgeting, among other financial behaviours; financial literacy increased as well.90 Participants in both the Saving Circle and SEED’s IDA programs reported that they continued to practice the financial habits (saving, money management) they learned after cash-out and had increased confidence managing their money.91 Momentum surveyed graduates of its matched savings program and found that 92 percent of respondents continued to save after exiting the program, 72 percent had emergency savings of at least $500, and 77 percent contributed to a registered savings account.92 Almost all (97 percent) responding alumni of Momentum’s Fair Gains program, which helps low-income youth save for post-secondary education, said they still save money every month; 86 percent of alumni reported that their financial situation had improved since they took the program, and 86 percent said they felt confident to deal with a financial emergency.93

Alumni of more intensive matched savings programs have cited social support from program staff and other participants as one of the most important non-financial factors contributing to their saving success. Graduates of SEED’s matched savings programs, for example, reported that a major strength of the program was the opportunity to work toward their saving goal in a group, the other members of which were in a similar situation and faced the same financial barriers.94 Participants valued the money-management training not just for the skills and habits they learned but also for the social support it provided. Through the training sessions, participants had the opportunity to make friends with others who faced similar barriers and challenges related to living in poverty.95 American IDA research has also found that social and psychological factors, not just economic factors, matter when it comes to saving success.96

Even the most intensive, IDA-style matched savings programs offer opportunities for cost savings and cost sharing. The combination of private deposits and public match credits leverages participants’ own capital and government investment, stretching both public and private dollars. Depending on the program, administrative costs may be lower, because the accounts are administered through private financial institutions. The free-rider effect that can occur in many social-assistance programs may be reduced in a matched savings system, since a private contribution is required to trigger a public contribution. There may be more opportunities for employers or private third parties to participate in the program given the shared risk and lower administrative cost.97

Indeed, many IDAs operate as public-private partnerships: governments develop the structure of the programs, non-profit organizations deliver the programs, and banks or credit unions hold participants’ deposits; funding is provided by both government and private sources.98

Expanding the role of financial institutions in order to streamline the delivery of matched savings programs may be an opportunity for efficiency gains.99 Banks and credit unions would not incur any extra expenses, since governments would use gambling profits to cover program costs.100

The government could reduce costs associated with the high-touch elements of the program by working with organizations that are already embedded in and have built high-touch relationships with their clients and communities, such as tax-filing volunteers, debt counsellors, and financial-assistance programs run by faith-based communities. IDA participants have stated in interviews and focus groups that it was the financial incentive that drew them to apply for the program, but it was the personal support they received that enabled them to succeed.101 Since this personalized support is both important and expensive, high-touch (and therefore high-cost) services should be carefully targeted to where they will have the greatest impact.102

Policy-makers could likewise reduce costs by taking advantage of existing administrative structures. If eligibility for future IDA programs were tied to existing means-tested programs with their own administrative databases, it might be possible to substantially reduce costs associated with recruitment, verification of eligibility, and enrolment.103 Targeted recruitment may help reduce windfall gains.104

Streamlining or eliminating the financial-management curriculum is another way to lower costs. One of the somewhat surprising findings of the learn$ave demonstration was that financial-management training had only a small incremental impact on savings outcomes, though participants expressed appreciation for the training. The program evaluation suggests several potential reasons for this result. The act of saving itself—as incentivized by the matching credits—may have been more important than learning about saving.105 Participants may have already been familiar with the content (many had fairly high levels of education). The training might have been effective for the very people who did not or could not apply. Participants might not have been able to apply the lessons they learned to their everyday financial lives due to economic hardship—institutional barriers rather than lack of knowledge may be more important in shaping saving behaviour.106 Moreover, while IDAs and other programs that include financial-management training often assume that low-income households have lower financial literacy and are less skilled at practices like budgeting, they may in fact be more skilled than are middle- and higher-income households.107

Despite these cost-saving opportunities, however, intensive matched savings programs tend to be quite expensive to administer. The high costs of getting participants started on the program—recruitment challenges are common, and verifying applicants’ eligibility is a labour-intensive (and thus expensive) process—mean fewer funds end up in participants’ pockets.108 The cash-out process and assistance provided to participants throughout the program also drive up costs. American IDAs, for example, were found to cost $64 per participant per month to administer (i.e., excluding the cost of the match), much more than other major savings products such as 401(k)s.109 Feedback from IDA alumni suggests that high-cost services are essential to the program—participants express appreciation for the personalized support, so eliminating the extra services to administer the program through the tax system would likely reduce its effectiveness.

High costs were a significant finding of the learn$ave demonstration: “The estimated cost per additional person prompted to enrol in an education program by learn$ave matched saving credits and services would be fairly high—around $38,000, at best.”110 The most expensive activities were recruiting participants, processing withdrawals, and case-management services (particularly for learn$ave-plus participants).111 However, the main reason the cost is so high is windfall gains—outcomes from the control group showed that the program funded many who would have enrolled in education without the added funds they accumulated through the program.112 Windfall gains are a common policy challenge, since participants in many publicly funded programs self-select: “The most motivated participate and benefit when they might have succeeded on their own without the program.”113 The total cost of the learn$ave demonstration was $30 million.114 Even if running a similar matched savings program did not involve any cost savings, provinces’ annual gambling profits run into the hundreds of millions (surpassing $1 billion in several provinces) and would provide ample revenue for a very substantial expansion of the program.

Critics have also raised questions about matched savings programs’ effectiveness at alleviating poverty. As discussed above, the government’s existing low-touch matched savings programs are underused by poorer Canadians. But high-touch, IDA-style programs do not appeal equally to all eligible low-income families—learn$ave participants were younger, had higher levels of formal education, were more likely to be single, were more likely to be employed, had higher incomes, and were more likely to have recently immigrated to Canada.115 This is consistent with other IDA and matched savings programs, which have found those with higher levels of education are disproportionately attracted to the program (and are more likely to complete it).116 These findings suggest a new matched savings program might leave some behind, including those who could most benefit from it. IDAs have also been criticized for not paying enough attention to the structural causes of poverty.117

Many participants are unsuccessful at saving. High dropout rates are common in IDAs: almost half (48 percent) of American Dream Demonstration participants were classified as non-savers (they saved nothing or less than $100).118 For those participants who do save, it is unclear whether they actually decrease consumption to meet their saving goals.119 Saving in the program does not necessarily prepare participants for other kinds of saving available outside the program, where the return on deposits will be much lower and financial coaching is less readily available. In the Saving Gateway evaluation, for example, participants wondered whether the match rate was the best way to build a saving habit that would persist after the program ended. They noted that the matching credits were quite different from and substantially higher than interest rates that would be available for conventional saving products.120

Evidence is mixed at best as to whether IDAs have a significant impact on asset accumulation or net worth in the long term.121 Though Loibl et al. found a positive association between program completion and household saving, the report also notes that it can’t determine causality: it may be that people who were already savers were more likely to complete the program.122 There is no statistically significant evidence of any link between participation in Saving Gateway—in which participants did not have to cash out their matched credits by the end of the program—and increased net worth.123 At least two follow-up studies of matched savings programs did not find any relationship between program participation and saving.124 Yet it is important to note the influence of program design on evaluations of net worth. The relatively short time frame of many IDAs and the requirement that participants cash out their savings mean that the long-term impact of the investment purchased through the program will likely not be evident until months if not years after the program’s end. For instance, learn$ave was expected to increase earnings in the long term, but researchers expected that these results, if they were to emerge, could not be observed by the fifty-four-month mark (which turned out to be true).125 Moreover, IDAs are premised on the assumption that the act of saving itself, rather than just the assets accumulated through saving, benefits the saver. Indeed, research suggests that the habit of saving is linked to improved feelings of accomplishment, financial control, independence, and security, as well as higher levels of perceived financial well-being.126

Conclusion

A matched savings program for low-income Canadians is one way to get gambling money out of provincial coffers and (back) into the bank accounts of the poor. Implementing such a program would not be without challenges, as the issues outlined in the previous section make clear. Nevertheless, there are several important advantages to using gambling profits to help low-income families build assets rather than using these funds to supplement income transfers. First, it helps fill the policy gap related to low-income savings incentives described above. Second, this approach avoids the problem of earmarked funds becoming expected funds—casino and lottery profits are a more volatile, less reliable source of provincial revenue than taxes, and an unexpected shortfall could be devastating for those who have razor-thin margins in their household budget and rely on government benefits to pay their monthly bills. If gambling profits fall, providers may not be able to offer matched savings accounts to as many clients or at as high a match rate that year, but no family will find their expected supply of income cut back.

A third, related advantage of the matched savings option is that, because it does not touch the existing income transfers and benefits system, the government is less likely to be tempted to avoid meaningful gambling reform by cutting expenses elsewhere. One of the dangers we hope to avoid is mere cosmetic tweaks that render pointless the very structural transformation of gambling finances that this report urges. If policy-makers put gambling profits in a separate poverty-alleviation fund, but then decrease the amount spent on poverty alleviation from the consolidated revenue fund, nothing will have changed. The government may have moved some money around, but it is still using gambling money to fund its core services. Adopting a matched savings approach would not eliminate this possibility, of course. But real change is possible: governments currently spend relatively little on asset-building for low-income families (compared to income transfers), and the community organizations and financial institutions delivering the matched savings programs would likely welcome an investment in their program, or at the very least have significant learnings to share and potential support to offer.

Option 3: Help build emergency funds by offering prize-linked savings

The government could also use gambling profits to fund a prize-linked-savings (PLS) initiative. PLS programs are offered by both governments and financial institutions in a variety of forms, but all encourage saving by offering participants the chance to win. In a PLS system, the money that would normally be paid separately to each participating savings account as fixed interest is pooled into a single prize fund; instead of earning regular interest, every participating saver has a chance to win. As with a traditional lottery, participants have the chance to hit the jackpot, but every PLS account holder keeps their deposits—the interest is awarded randomly, but the principal is never lost.127

Though relatively little-used in Canada, PLS programs are quite popular worldwide. From bank accounts featuring the chance to win a car in Brazil, to prize bonds in Ireland or Denmark, to the “multimillionaire” accounts offered by Pakistani banks, to the Kenya Post Office Savings Bank’s premium bonds, to the special draws for a Mercedes at Oman International Bank, the opportunity to win big has inspired savers across the globe.128 This paper will focus on three different PLS programs available in jurisdictions similar to Canada—namely, the United States and the United Kingdom.

In the past decade or so, PLS programs have become a major initiative among American credit unions. Save To Win, the largest of these programs, has seen great success across the United States since its launch by Michigan credit unions and the non-profit Commonwealth (formerly Doorway to Dreams or D2D Fund) in 2009. With only a small deposit of $25, members can open a twelve-month share certificate and earn entries into drawings for prizes, which usually range from $25 to $5,000. Every $25 deposited earns account holders an additional entry into the prize draw, up to a maximum of ten entries each month.129 Organizations advocating for improving Americans’ financial security convinced Congress of the policy potential of PLS programs, leading to the passage of the American Savings Promotion Act with broad support in December 2014.130 This legislation enabled PLS products at the federal level in the United States, paving the way for authorizing legislation at the state level and an expansion of PLS. At time of writing, thirty-three states allowed PLS.131

More recently, American retail giant Walmart introduced PLS to millions of Americans through its highly successful MoneyCard Vault. Customers with a Walmart MoneyCard, a prepaid debit card, can transfer a portion of their balance into the Vault, a free savings feature from which funds cannot be spent directly. Every dollar saved in the MoneyCard Vault earns the saver an entry in the month’s prize drawing, up to a maximum of five hundred entries. There are 1,000 prizes to be won each month: 999 prizes worth $25 each, and one $1,000 grand prize.132 In spring 2020, Walmart encouraged MoneyCard holders to deposit their pandemic stimulus checks directly into their Vault, offering waived maintenance fees and quick access.133

Among the largest and most popular national PLS products are Premium Bonds, offered by Britain’s National Savings and Investments, a government department and Executive Agency of the Chancellor of the Exchequer. The program’s history stretches back to UK “Million Adventure” of 1694, which Britain developed to manage its debt from the Nine Years’ War of 1689–1697. A total of 100,000 tickets, sold at £10 apiece, offered their holders £1 each year until 1710. A small percentage of the tickets would win their holders between £10 and £1,000 each year for those sixteen years.134 The current Premium Bonds program officially launched in 1956 to curb inflation and encourage saving in the aftermath of World War II. On the first day of the program alone, eager investors bought £5 million worth of bonds (nearly $218 million in 2020 Canadian dollars).135 Today, customers can buy prize-linked Premium Bonds from National Savings and Investments for £1 each. The annual prize fund interest rate is 1.40 percent; instead of earning this interest on their bonds directly, buyers have a shot at winning between £25 and £1 million in tax-free prizes each month. Every bond number gets a separate entry in the draw, an incentive to save more.136

Policy benefits and disadvantages

PLS programs have proved popular among customers. Credit union members saved almost $200 million—and were awarded $3 million in prizes—in Save To Win’s first decade of operation. Since 2009, the program has expanded from eight credit unions in Michigan to 127 credit unions in sixteen states, with an additional 107 credit unions in nine other states introducing their own versions of PLS products; over 110,000 cumulative individual PLS accounts have been opened, and the average member saved over $2,000.137 Walmart customers moved more than $2 billion through the MoneyCard Vault after the program’s launch in August 2016.138 Premium Bonds are immensely popular in the UK: twenty-one million Britons—almost a third of the country’s population—had nearly £80 million (CA$137 million) invested in these bonds at the start of 2019.139 The Million-a-Month Account (MaMa), a PLS program offered by First National Bank in South Africa, was another hugely popular product. Within 18 months of the program’s launch, PLS accounts outnumbered the bank’s regular saving accounts.140 In fact, evidence from several lab-based experiments suggests that PLS products encourage individuals to save at a higher rate than do accounts offering standard interest.141

Studies of PLS products have consistently found that PLS is particularly appealing to low-income savers. Among PLS account holders in American credit unions, 85–93 percent were classified as financially vulnerable: “not regular savers, asset poor, low to moderate income, had high debt, or had no emergency savings.”142 The relative appeal of Premium Bonds is strongest among lower-income households.143 Tufano, De Neve, and Maynard surveyed Walmart customers and found that respondents with less than $2,000 in assets were two and a half times more likely to express interest in PLS programs than those with $50,000 or more.144 In an online lab experiment, Atalay et al. found that the introduction of PLS increased total saving and that the result was stronger among participants with the lowest reported income.145 The strong appeal of PLS among lower-income savers may be related to the low return these savers can expect from conventional interest, particularly if the account is intended to serve as an emergency fund. Compound interest can yield a significant return over time, but those with constrained incomes are likely to have smaller balances and need more liquidity in their savings.146 Regular interest would provide little more than pocket change for a low-income single mother who’s able to accumulate only $1,000 and needs to withdraw most of it for an emergency car repair after six months. Losing the few dollars she would earn by putting her money in a standard savings account won’t have a noticeable impact on her standard of living. Winning a $1,000 prize, in contrast, would significantly improve her financial situation.

PLS can also help non-savers develop a saving habit. Evidence suggests that PLS products are attractive to those who report low to nonexistent rates of formal saving.147 The survey conducted by Tufano, De Neve, and Maynard, for instance, found that those without regular savings plans were 70 percent more likely to express interest in PLS.148 In Atalay et al.’s experiment, the increase in saving observed after the introduction of PLS was stronger among participants with the lowest reported savings.149 Another lab experiment, conducted by Filiz-Ozbay et al., found evidence that the appeal of PLS was strongest among those with low bank-account balances.150 A survey of participants in WINcentive, a PLS account offered by the Minnesota Credit Union Network, found that one-third (33 percent) did not save before opening their WINcentive account. The majority (57 percent) of these non-savers said they now save a fixed amount regularly; only 8 percent reported that they still do not save.151 Given their appeal to non-savers, many PLS products are designed to encourage savers to start small and contribute what they can. The minimum Premium Bond investment is £25 (CA$44), manageable even for those with constrained incomes.152 Opening a WINcentive account requires just $5. Savers earn an entry into the monthly, quarterly, and yearly prize draws with each $25 deposit and can earn up to four entries each month.153 Customers who took advantage of the WINcentive option generally saved more than their comparable counterparts who didn’t use the program.154

It can be difficult to discern whether observed saving in PLS is genuinely new saving or simply moving accounts from one form of saving to another (i.e., cannibalizing existing saving), but evidence so far points to saving in PLS as new saving. High rollover levels—account holders reopening their certificates of deposit after the original twelve-month term ends—also point to the potential of PLS products to incentivize long-term saving.155 Indeed, the introduction of PLS may encourage other kinds of saving as well. At least two recent studies have found that offering PLS increases saving in both PLS and conventional savings accounts. Cole, Iverson, and Tufano’s analysis of account-level data on First National Bank’s MaMa program supports this result: “We do not see any evidence that the MaMa program cannibalized savings, and instead find the reverse: branches with higher MaMa usage also saw expansion of regular savings, and individuals who opened MaMa accounts typically increased their balances in standard savings accounts. Evidence from the random awarding of prizes suggest that these relationships may be causal.”156 Similarly, Jindapon, Sujarittanonta, and Viriyavipart find that the introduction of PLS increases saving in both PLS and traditional savings (TS) vehicles: “When subjects are allowed to save in a PLS account in addition to a TS account, most of them choose to save in both. Most importantly, their total savings increase.”157

Importantly, researchers have found evidence that PLS is appealing to lottery players and that at least some of the new saving in these accounts comes from a reduction in lottery spending. PLS does not cannibalize other forms of saving, but acts as a partial substitute for gambling—a substitute, importantly, that builds personal assets rather than state revenues. Tufano, De Neve, and Maynard found that respondents who reported spending at least $100 on lottery and gambling activity in the past six months were almost three times more likely to show interest in PLS than those who had spent less than $100.158

Atalay et al. found in a lab experiment that the introduction of PLS incited participants to increase their saving by cutting back on spending, including lottery spending: “The introduction of PLS indeed increases total savings quite dramatically (on average by 12% points), and [the] demand for the PLS account comes from reductions in lottery expenditures as well as current consumption. Hence PLS leads to genuinely new savings, and even generates new savers.”159

Outside lab settings, Cole, Iverson, and Tufano used MaMa account data to demonstrate that “PLS participants tend to significantly increase overall savings rates and that at least some of this increase in net savings comes from reduced lottery play.”160 Cookson analyzed data from casino cash withdrawals to study the effect of the introduction of PLS to Nebraska on casino-gambling expenditures. He finds that “PLS substitutes strongly for gambling” and that “the introduction of savings lotteries reduces the amount of casino gambling. That is, households’ newfound opportunity to gamble while saving in STW [Save To Win] accounts is a strong substitute for gambling at commercial casinos. . . . individuals who were exposed to savings lotteries were 15 percentage points less likely to visit the casino in the post period.”161

It is possible that this substitution effect could be amplified if saving in a PLS account were as easy as buying a lottery ticket. Lottery tickets can be found behind every convenience- and grocery-store counter—why shouldn’t savings opportunities be equally ubiquitous? Commonwealth (formerly D2D Fund) has proposed taking advantage of the lottery’s existing footprint and infrastructure to sell savings tickets. It conducted a market-research survey and found strong interest in such a product, with appeal widespread across diverse demographic groups.162 Holmes likewise recommends explicitly marketing PLS as an alternative to the lottery to encourage substitution for lottery expenditure. Credit unions could take advantage of the lottery’s reach by “[selling] scratch-off tickets behind the counter at convenience stores. Each ticket would yield a prize (varying, perhaps, from $5 to $25) that the bearer could use as an initial deposit in a new PLS account.”163

Like IDAs, PLS products can promote financial inclusion since they serve people who are less likely to use formal savings products.164 Commonwealth’s report on PLS at credit unions noted that many of those who opened PLS accounts had never used a formal savings product before. In fact, up to 19 percent of PLS account holders cited the PLS product as the reason they joined their credit union. Between three-fifths and four-fifths (60–78 percent) of PLS account holders said that building their savings would make them more likely to use their credit union’s other financial products.165 Walmart’s MoneyCard Vault—on a prepaid card offered not by a bank or credit union, but by a retailer—is America’s largest single PLS program.166 Prepaid cards are common among unbanked and underbanked populations who are excluded from or do not feel comfortable accessing mainstream financial institutions.167 Though the unbanked are a lower proportion of the population in Canada than in the United States,168 prepaid cards are a growing market in Canada, particularly among younger Canadians and those making under $40,000 a year.169 Increasing financial inclusion for unbanked and underbanked people not only improves their financial security but also benefits society as a whole since their funds are no longer stashed under a mattress but are at work in the economy.170

Unlike IDAs, however, there is a solid business case to be made for financial institutions to offer PLS products. A PLS account is cheaper and easier to administer than an IDA, which is a strong selling point for both businesses and policy-makers.171 Unlike a matched savings account, the financial incentive that attracts customers to a PLS product does not impose substantial additional costs on the financial institutions that offer it, since what they pay in prizes is no more than what they would otherwise be paying in guaranteed interest.172 These products would be easy to explain to potential customers, since everyone knows what a lottery is and how it works; easy to produce, since no complex investment management is needed; and easy to keep liquid, since those who withdraw their funds can simply have their total entries reduced (as long as they maintain some balance).173 As decades of lottery marketing have made clear, winners are a great promotion opportunity.174 Cole, Iverson, and Tufano demonstrate that prize-winning affects the saving behaviour of both winners and witnesses: those who won a MaMa prize tended to substantially increase their account balance (sometimes by even more than the value of their prize), and a branch that awarded a large prize would experience a surge in demand for the PLS product in the month that followed.175

It is nevertheless important to remember that PLS is not a panacea for low-income households’ financial security. The evidence on whether using PLS reliably builds good financial habits remains somewhat limited. Though survey research and lab experiments have yielded promising results, systematic empirical research demonstrating the long-term impact of PLS participation on savings habits and financial inclusion is currently unavailable.176 Nor has every study been equally promising. One 2019 study examined whether prize-linked incentives were effective at helping borrowers reduce their debt burdens and found that “prize-linked incentives may simply attract individuals who are already more likely to repay their debts, and not causally change behavior.”177 In addition, although many PLS programs have been designed with low-income savers in mind, the ability to increase one’s odds of winning by increasing one’s savings account balance can have a regressive effect that disadvantages those at the bottom of the income distribution. Lowest-income participants, who have the least disposable income to contribute, may have the lowest chance of winning a prize, since they can’t purchase as many entries into the draw as their higher-income counterparts.178 However, many PLS programs, including Save To Win and WINcentive, do limit the number of entries that account holders can earn each month, providing an incentive to save more while still keeping the playing field relatively level for those with more constrained incomes. Moreover, a regressive effect on one’s chance of winning is still an improvement over the regressive effect of taxation under the current lottery system.

The provinces’ monopoly on gambling means that offering PLS products on a wide scale would require overcoming regulatory barriers. According to Canada’s Criminal Code, only provincial governments (or organizations granted provincial licenses, such as fairs or charities) can operate lotteries or other games of chance. A program meets the definition of an illegal lottery if it consists of three elements: a prize, chance, and “consideration”—that is, something of value that participants are required to provide in order to be eligible to win the prize. If a company wants to run a promotional contest in Canada featuring, say, a draw for a grand prize, it has to remove one of those three elements for its contest to be legal. This is why contest rules often require winners to answer a skill-testing question (making the contest a game of mixed chance and skill rather than a game of pure chance) and/or include the clause that there is “no purchase necessary” to win (removing the element of consideration).179 Since a standard PLS product would include all three elements of a lottery—participation requires depositing money at the issuing institution, and winners of cash prizes are chosen by chance—an institution offering PLS products would have to use one of these openings to operate legally in Canada. In the PLS feature of savings app QUBER, for example, winners are required to answer a skill-testing question before they can claim their prize.180 Removing these regulatory barriers would make it easier for financial institutions to offer PLS to their customers. Given the risks already involved in developing a new product, possible legal issues might discourage banks and credit unions from investing in a PLS program. Amending Canadian legislation to enable PLS may seem like a daunting task, but the American experience is promising. In 2014, the American Savings Promotion Act, which authorized financial institutions to offer PLS and exempted PLS products from lottery prohibitions in the federal criminal code, was passed with bipartisan support.181 One of the many advantages of PLS is that it appeals to politicians on both sides of the aisle: PLS programs are designed with the goal of helping low-income households get out of poverty, but through promoting responsible financial habits for individuals and enabling financial institutions to offer innovative, consumer-friendly products.182

Yet bipartisan political support does not mean universal support, and the gambling industry may fight back if it senses competition invading their market. Despite—or perhaps because of—its widespread popularity, South Africa’s MaMa program lasted only three years. The government forced First National Bank to end the program after the South African Lottery Board sued to have it shut down as an illegal lottery.183 The gambling industry’s opposition to the program suggests that saving in PLS may have been, at the very least, perceived to be cannibalizing consumers’ lottery spending and as such represented a threat to the lottery’s bottom line. Given emerging evidence that consumers do reduce their gambling spending to save in PLS accounts, a Canadian PLS program could meet with similar opposition from the gambling industry, a risk likely to grow as the program expanded. On the other hand, the fact that Canada’s gambling sector is operated by provincial governments rather than private businesses may reduce this risk.

Nor is easing regulatory restrictions sufficient in itself to bring PLS to potential savers. Financial institutions need to be on board to offer PLS products and promote them to their customers. The American experience suggests that participation is not guaranteed. Michigan was one of the first states to pass PLS-enabling legislation, but four years after Save To Win was introduced, less than a fifth (17 percent) of the state’s credit-union members had access to the PLS program. Even though PLS was legal it was mostly unavailable, since relatively few people banked at institutions that offered Save To Win.184 Credit unions have been leading the way with PLS products in the United States, but that still puts PLS out of reach of most Americans, since most use banks and banks have been slow on the PLS uptake.185 Part of the problem is that lower-income people are by definition less profitable to financial institutions than high-income customers, who can be underwritten for mortgages and charged asset-management fees. For conventional banks, whose mandate requires making a profit for shareholders, focusing on these high-income customers may be more attractive than investing in small-dollar savings programs for those with few assets.186 PLS products may be more suited to credit unions with their non-profit mandate and focus on community development, or to fintech start-ups focused on innovation. The government could also use gambling proceeds to help innovative organizations cover the costs of getting new PLS programs off the ground.

Moreover, the availability of a PLS product does not guarantee mass enrollment. A study by the Pew Charitable Trusts found that take-up of PLS accounts at credit unions that offer them is relatively low: the typical credit union with a PLS product saw only 1.3 percent of its members open an account.187 These low figures stand in stark contrast to the popularity and ubiquity of Premium Bonds in the United Kingdom. This may be due to the latter’s longer history: British PLS had a half-century head start on its American counterpart.188 The postal system also gave Premium Bonds a competitive edge. Though National Savings and Investments discontinued post-office sales in 2015, distribution through a well-trafficked public institution made the Premium Bond program highly accessible for most of its history.189 Since credit unions and fintech start-ups generally operate on a much smaller scale than banks—particularly in Canada, where five or six banks dominate the market—they may lack the reach needed to make PLS products widely available. If savings tickets were to be offered alongside lottery tickets, we recommend that the government work with existing ticket retailers (such as grocery and convenience stores) to ensure as broad a market as possible. Bringing lottery retailers on board makes good policy as well as good politics: for many of these retailers, the commissions they earn on lottery-ticket sales are an important source of revenue, and they are more likely to support a new PLS product if it contributes to rather than competes with their bottom line. In order to protect the business model of ticket retailers while keeping costs low for the financial institutions offering the new savings accounts, the government could pay commissions to retailers for selling savings tickets equal to the commissions paid for lottery tickets (using proceeds from its gambling fund, of course). Given the increasing popularity of both online banking and online shopping, savings tickets should be available online as well.190

Despite evidence that PLS deposits are financed at least in part by cutting back on gambling spending, PLS prizes will struggle to compete with the lottery’s large jackpots. Large prizes are key to PLS programs’ effectiveness. Though smaller, more frequent prizes are important to prevent program fatigue from the low likelihood of winning, research suggests that account holders are willing to accept lower small and medium prizes in exchange for larger jackpots.191 This is consistent with gambling research demonstrating that large jackpots, rather than improved odds of winning, drive up participation.192 PLS prizes will never be as large as lottery prizes, however, since PLS participants keep their principal and issuers still need to cover administrative and other expenses. PLS programs may also be negatively affected by “jackpot fatigue”: among traditional lotteries, the size of jackpots required to create a surge in sales has been increasing as customers’ idea of a large jackpot grows ever bigger, which makes PLS prizes seem increasingly small and likely carries over to PLS prize fatigue.193 This challenge suggests that promoting PLS products to potential savers is another place where government could put gambling revenue to good use: lottery and casino profits could be used to fund marketing campaigns for new PLS products, both the new savings tickets at the convenience-store counter and the new products available at local credit unions.

Given our earlier arguments about the poor financial habits that gambling encourages, critics might reasonably question whether PLS products are simply gambling in another form. Should we be promoting a product that appeals to users because of (not even in spite of) their skewed perceptions? Should we be encouraging people to save by exploiting the same cognitive biases as the lottery does?194 Lottery marketing takes advantage of and encourages availability bias—our tendency to overestimate the likelihood of something happening based on how easily we can envision it—by heavily advertising winners so that available information skews customers’ beliefs about the odds of winning.195 What if PLS backfires, and winning prizes through the program (or seeing others win) makes savers more likely to overestimate their chance of winning the lottery?196 We believe, however, that PLS products are a viable step in the right direction when it comes to financial habits.197 Prize-linked saving is still saving. If non-savers are attracted to PLS by the same desire for risk that would otherwise be fulfilled with a lottery ticket, we consider that a win.

Conclusion

Prize-linked-savings products have their limitations, but they have strong potential as an innovative response to the savings challenge. Critics may point out that a PLS account is not the best place for someone to park his or her money—the magic of compound interest means investments, or even a standard savings account offering regular interest, would yield a greater return over time. We agree that PLS may not be the best option for large, long-term investments, such as retirement savings. They are, however, an excellent option as an emergency savings vehicle. The point of a rainy-day fund isn’t to grow through accumulated interest but to act as a buffer in case of an unexpected expense. Between low interest rates and the relatively small amounts saved—particularly in the case of low-income savers—the interest earned on emergency funds would amount to little more than pocket change; account holders are unlikely to notice a few extra dollars (or the lack thereof) a year. Compound interest is at best a weak incentive to save in these cases.198 Winning a thousand dollars, however, is quite another story. In our opinion, giving up an insignificant amount of regular interest payments for the chance to win a substantial prize makes good financial sense. Indeed, many PLS account holders are using their accounts to build emergency savings. When the Minnesota Credit Union Network surveyed participants in its PLS product WINcentive, a rainy-day fund was the most commonly cited savings goal—40 percent of respondents said they were building emergency savings.199

Option 4: Increase problem-gambling funding out of provincial gambling corporations’ marketing budgets

Up to this point, the policy options we review in this paper have focused on helping the poor, since they bear a disproportionate share of the burden of state-run gambling. Our fourth and final policy suggestion aims to help the other group most harmed by gambling: problem gamblers. Recent research identifies around 0.6 percent of Canadians as problem gamblers, with an additional 2.7 percent identified as at-risk gamblers.200 Yet it is crucial to remember that these seemingly small figures conceal the broader impact of problem gambling on families and communities. Fully one in four Canadians (26 percent) report being personally affected by problem gambling—that is, they either have a close friend or family member struggling with this addiction or have gambling problems themselves. Of this group, nearly two in three (65 percent) say the problem gambler suffered a significant economic loss—such as losing a car or house or going heavily into debt—as a result of their gambling.201

Though those classified as having a gambling problem make up a very small proportion of the population in any given province, they are responsible for a large share of gambling revenue. In Ontario, problem gamblers make up 1–2 percent of the population and contribute up to 24 percent of gambling revenue; in British Columbia, 4–5 percent contribute up to 26 percent; in Alberta, 2–3 percent contribute up to 50 percent; and in the Atlantic provinces, 1–2 percent contribute up to 30 percent (see Figure 7).202

For more information, see “Pressing Its Luck,” page 16-20.

Yet the budgets of provincial gambling corporations suggest that provinces’ priorities are skewed heavily in favour of marketing—that is, encouraging people to gamble more—rather than prevention and treatment of problem gambling. In 2018, the Ontario Lottery and Gaming Corporation spent $282 million on marketing and promotion but only $64 million on problem-gambling prevention and treatment: $45 million was directed to the Ontario Ministry of Health and Long-Term Care, as per a policy that earmarks 2 percent of gross slot-machine revenue for problem gambling, and $19 million was devoted to its own Responsible Gambling program.203 In other words, Ontario Lottery and Gaming is spending four and a half times as much on marketing as it does on gambling addictions. The same pattern is true in BC: the British Columbia Lottery Corporation dedicated just $5.6 million to responsible gambling strategies in 2019, but spent $26 million—nearly five times more—on advertising, marketing, and promotions. Put in context of these two corporations’ total annual revenues, Ontario Lottery and Gaming and British Columbia Lottery are spending on problem-gambling mitigation just 0.8 percent and 0.2 percent, respectively, of the money they make each year ($7.5 billion and $2.6 billion) (see Figures 8 through 11).204

If the goal of provincial governments is to promote the well-being of its citizens more than boost its bottom line, these figures should at the very least be rebalanced. A reversal of this ratio would be ideal; better still would be cutting the marketing line from provincial gambling corporations’ budgets altogether. At minimum, policy-makers should mandate that Ontario Lottery and Gaming Corporation and British Columbia Lottery Corporation (and their counterparts in other provinces, for which marketing and problem-gambling expenditure data were not available) halve their advertising budgets and put the difference toward problem-gambling reduction initiatives so that these corporations spend at least as much on helping those who gamble too much as they do on convincing people to gamble more.

Policy benefits and disadvantages

The first and most obvious benefit of this policy is that it would provide more money for problem-gambling research, prevention, and treatment. As with poverty-reduction strategies, money is being used to help the groups disproportionately harmed by the expansion of gambling. Provinces could choose where to spend the money, based on provincial needs and priorities. Some of the funds could be dedicated to awareness and prevention. This could include educational campaigns to inform the public of the harms of gambling or boosting the capacity of provincial gambling corporations’ in-house responsible-gambling programs, such as Ontario Lottery and Gaming’s PlaySmart, British Columbia Lottery Corporation and Alberta Gaming, Liquor and Cannabis Corporation’s GameSense, or Atlantic Lottery Corporation’s PlayWise. Governments could allocate more funds to frontline services and treatment, including problem-gambling helplines, addiction counselling, and credit- and debt-counselling organizations. Prevention and treatment initiatives would be strengthened by investments in gambling research, providing resources on problem-gambling prevalence, demographic trends, risk factors, best practices for responsible gambling, and effective treatments.205

Cutting back on advertising could also reduce governments’ intentional stimulation of demand for gambling. If the purpose of investing in advertising is to encourage people to gamble more than they would without exposure to the advertising, it follows that less advertising could lead to less gambling. (And if there turns out to be no reduction in gambling behaviour after significant cuts to the marketing line, it would seem that those dollars would have been better spent elsewhere.) Research evidence suggests that higher exposure to gambling advertising is associated with both greater intention to gamble in the future and increased gambling behaviour. That is, those exposed to more gambling ads tended to gamble more often and to spend more money when they did.206 We agree that people who desire to gamble should have an outlet for it, and the best institution to ensure that gambling is safe and fair is the state. Yet there is no good reason for a state to try to increase the amount its citizens gamble, since there is no benefit apart from increased revenue and—as we have argued extensively in our earlier papers—collecting revenue in this way is unjust and predatory.207 The duty to minimize harms rather than maximize revenue is the very reason we believe that the state, not private corporations, should run the province’s gambling industry—the bottom line for a business is profit, but the bottom line for a just government is the well-being of its people.

While cash-strapped provinces may protest any loss of revenue, less money to Canada’s gambling industry may not be a bad thing. Defenders of the gambling industry argue that casinos create jobs, but are these the best kinds of jobs for the state to be creating? Critics have countered that “most of the jobs created in gambling only substitute one for one (at best) for the jobs destroyed when expenditure switches from other activities.”208 In a recent study, Marionneau and Nikkinen systematically reviewed the evidence on gambling’s impact on other industries. They find that the influence of gambling on local economies is mixed at best. While destination gambling (gambling used mainly by tourists, such as in Las Vegas or Atlantic City) can benefit nearby hospitality-related businesses or real estate, the impact of convenience gambling (gambling used mainly by locals) is mostly harmful to local economies.209 Most Canadian casinos extract virtually all of their revenue from local populations—often at the expense of other local businesses—rather than bringing in new money through tourism.210 Even Canadian casinos located near the border with the US draw most of their revenue from Canadians: Caesar’s Windsor and Ontario’s two Niagara casinos, the province’s largest border venues, collect only 35 percent and 3 percent of their revenue, respectively, from American patrons.211

It is also important to remember that when taxpayers stop spending money on gambling, that money does not disappear. It may be saved—and if these savings are deposited at a financial institution, the funds will be invested in other areas of the economy—or spent on other taxable activities. A comprehensive national report on gambling commissioned by the Australian government concluded that if gambling were scaled back, “some tax revenue would be lost. However, spending diverted from gambling would still be taxed, so the actual loss in revenue would not be equivalent to the apparent loss in revenue.”212

Funnelling gambling dollars into the provincial treasury is an easy way for governments to get a quick infusion of cash, but is not a sustainable source of revenue in the long term. Encouraging Ontarians to gamble more just moves the province’s money around, circulating citizens’ dollars rather than directing them toward value-added production.213 Gambling’s reliance on the appetite of local populations also raises the risk of diminishing returns as the consumer base loses interest. While the early years of gambling legalization saw the newly legal industry expand rapidly, the growth in provinces’ gambling revenue has slowed dramatically since the late 1990s as the novelty of casinos wore off (see Figures 12 and 13).214 Recent research has found that gambling participation in Canada has declined from nearly four-fifths (77.2 percent) in 2002 to around two-thirds (66.2 percent) in 2018. (Meanwhile, gambling revenue per Canadian adult has remained stable over the same period, meaning that the spending per gambler has increased.)215 Lotteries, for example, have been experiencing a demographic-driven decline in sales, with millennials buying fewer tickets than older generations. Ontario Lottery and Gaming’s market research has found that adults younger than thirty-five are less than half as likely as the average Ontarian to be a “current player,” that is, to have bought a lottery ticket in the past two months (15 percent compared to 38 percent). In contrast, adults older than fifty-five play the lottery at a significantly higher rate than the provincial average, with nearly half (46 percent) of that age group classified as a current player.216

Figure 12

Figure 13

Lotteries and casinos are also a highly inefficient way for the government to generate revenue. Provinces and other levels of government—including federal, municipal, and First Nations—get barely half the money that leaves gamblers’ pockets: in the 2018–19 fiscal year, the proportion of gambling revenue sent to governments totaled 38 percent in Ontario, 40 percent in Atlantic Canada, and 55 percent in Alberta and British Columbia (see Figures 14 through 17).217 The rest of the money goes to operating expenses and to lottery prizes—wealth skimmed from the pockets of the many, to be concentrated in the hands of the very, very few. As recent reporting has pointed out, the past few years have seen Ontario Lottery and Gaming’s profits fall even as revenue rises, raising questions about Ontario Lottery and Gaming Corporation executives’ compensation.218 Of course, as leaders of a multi-billion-dollar organization, members of the corporation’s executive team are exactly the kind of experienced and capable professionals Ontario would need to restructure its gambling system toward saving; their skills and expertise would be better spent building the wealth of individuals rather than funnelling ever more revenue to the state.Figures 14 - 17

Greater restrictions on gambling advertising would help align the policy framework for gambling with the regulatory approach used for other “sin tax” products, such as alcohol, tobacco, and cannabis. Provincial gambling corporations’ aggressive promotion strategy is conspicuously inconsistent with the marketing restrictions for other government-controlled “vices.” Advertising regulations for alcohol and tobacco are strictly worded so as to prevent artificial stimulation of demand. In Ontario, for example, an alcohol commercial is permitted only if it “promotes a general brand or type of liquor and not the consumption of liquor in general.”219 Tobacco products and accessories cannot even be visible to consumers until after they’ve been purchased, and cigarette packages are plastered with labels that urge consumers to stop smoking, often with graphic images.220 The government restrains the market for these products because it knows that unhealthy consumption—more of a risk when they’re more easily available—has social costs. As a money-draining form of entertainment with a potential for devastating addiction, gambling falls into the same category.221 Yet Ontario Lottery and Gaming provides 24/7 access to slots and urges Ontarians to try them out with messages like “Your fun starts here.”222

Rebalancing gambling corporations’ budgets to ensure that problem gambling receives at least as much funding as advertising is a sound first step. But this policy option has important limits. Reducing advertising and boosting problem-gambling funding are, on their own, unlikely to substantially reduce the prevalence of problem gambling. A review of evidence and best practices to prevent problem gambling notes that “educational strategies tend to have limited ability to prevent addictive behaviour, and that meaningful policy measures are usually more effective.”223 The authors find that information and awareness campaigns, on-site responsible-gambling centres, problem-gambling training for employees of gambling venues, and statistical instruction (i.e., educating players about the odds of different games) have moderately low effectiveness. In contrast, substantial restrictions on the number and location of gambling venues, on more harmful gambling formats, and on concurrent use of alcohol and tobacco have moderately high effectiveness.224

Moreover, very few problem gamblers seek treatment—likely only one in ten at most, according to available data. While the figures are higher for pathological gamblers—those with the most severe gambling problems—they are also the smallest group; low- or moderate-risk gamblers, whose gambling problems are milder, are a much larger group and as such experience the most gambling harms overall. Low treatment rates may suggest a need to improve the supply and accessibility of treatment, rather than a lack of demand, but more funding for treatment is unlikely to have more than a small impact on problem-gambling prevalence rates if only a small fraction of problem gamblers use the treatment.225 In contrast, a policy that includes meaningful restrictions on the supply of gambling affects everyone experiencing gambling harm. One of the factors linked to problem gambling is gambling availability—a national survey of problem gambling in Canada found the highest rates of gambling problems in provinces with permanent casinos alongside high concentrations of video lottery terminals (VLTs),226 and there is evidence that proximity to gambling venues is associated with problem gambling.227

Including the supply side in problem-gambling prevention strategies is consistent with a public health approach to gambling, which involves shifting focus away from the behaviour and responsibility of individuals to the systemic factors affecting gambling harm.228 In addition, policies restricting supply are consistent with the state’s approach to other potentially dangerous products: “Jurisdictional approaches to reducing the harm from tobacco, alcohol, motor vehicles, etc., consistently give equal if not higher priority to policy initiatives (i.e., restricting access and operation), so it is unclear why gambling should be limited to just educational initiatives.”229 Educational initiatives are important, but are less effective on their own—or when policy measures give the opposite message. This might mean ending twenty-four-hour access to casinos, restricting loyalty programs that stretch out players’ losing streaks with complimentary rewards, barring casinos from offering complimentary alcohol to gamblers, or limiting the number of electronic gambling machines and implementing stricter regulations on their deceptive features (e.g., losses disguised as wins and near misses).230

231

Reduce Reliance on and Supply of Electronic Gambling Machines: A major risk factor for problem gambling is electronic gambling machines (EGMs). EGMs include slot machines, which are found in casinos, and VLTs, which are found in licensed bars and pubs. EGMs are designed to override players’ self-control of their spending and playtime with features that make them think they’re closer to winning, or are winning more often, than they actually are. These deceptive features include losses disguised as wins, where audio and visual effects celebrate a player “winning” an amount less than he or she wagered even though the player lost money, and near misses, where the display of symbols makes it appear that the player was close to winning even though the outcome of each play is completely random. These features manipulate players’ emotional and cognitive perceptions of the game to keep them playing longer and spending more. One study of gambling and problem gambling in Prince Edward Island found that someone who played VLTs in the past year was thirty-eight times more likely to have a significant gambling problem than someone who never touched a VLT. Meanwhile, EGMs are the most lucrative gambling format for provincial governments: even in provinces where VLTs are illegal (Ontario and BC), EGMs are responsible for more gambling profits than every other format combined (see Figures 18 through 21). Researchers in Alberta found that up to 77 percent of VLT profits and 72 percent of slot-machine profits come from problem gamblers. If governments are to reduce their financial reliance on those most vulnerable to severe gambling harm, they must end their reliance on profits extracted through EGMs.

Conclusion

“Contrary to notions current in North American society, the maximizing of national wealth and the raising of our living standards is not the principal responsibility of government. . . . It is the undeniable and irrevocable obligation of governments to rule with justice for all and with charity towards the weak and powerless.”232 A government should promote healthy economic growth, yes, but this should always be subordinate to its defining responsibility to administer justice for the common good.233 The provinces’ dependency on gambling money compromises this duty. The ways in which gambling affects individuals should not distract us from the broader injustice of a state that relies on a robust gambling industry to pay its bills: “To associate all the evils of gambling with personal choice is to overlook the complicity of a system that needs gamblers in order to flourish.”234

Conclusion

In this paper we examined ways in which policy-makers could reform their use of gambling funds so that these profits work for, not against, low-income households. We provided four policy options that would disentangle gambling dollars from legitimate tax revenue while helping the poor build both saving habits and assets.

A cash-transfer program, which we’ve provisionally named the Gaming Savings Credit, is the simplest option. It would be easy for constituents to understand, relatively straightforward to implement (particularly if designers take advantage of existing benefits infrastructure), and have the potential to reduce income inequality by boosting the incomes of the poor. Research shows that recipients of these kinds of unconditional cash-transfer programs generally spend the funds in line with the intention of the policy. Such a program does not address the gap in savings incentives for the poor, however. While the program could be oriented toward saving by adding a tax-time incentive to set Gaming Savings Credit money aside, such an addition would eliminate the very simplicity that this policy option has as one of its core strengths.

Another option is to use gambling profits to fund a matched savings program, which would stretch both public and private dollars by adding a government contribution to an individual’s savings. This incentive has been an effective way to build savings habits among participants in matched savings programs, from non-profits’ small-scale interventions at tax time to intensive, state-funded individual development accounts (IDAs). In program evaluations, alumni report higher levels of saving, and saving more regularly, after participating in the program, spurred on by the financial incentive and support from their fellow participants. Yet windfall gains and high administrative costs mean these benefits often come with a steep price tag, and evidence on their long-term effectiveness at reducing poverty remains inconclusive.

The most immediate course of action that policy-makers could take is to reduce provincial gambling corporations’ marketing budgets and put the money toward problem-gambling research, prevention, and treatment. Problem gamblers are responsible for a vastly disproportionate share of total gambling revenue, and the most addictive gambling format—electronic gambling machines or EGMs—is also the most lucrative. Yet available data suggest provinces are investing far more in ads encouraging citizens to gamble than they are in services and research to help problem gamblers. Balancing this ratio (or, better yet, reversing it) would reflect a shift in governments’ priorities, from the maximization of profit to the protection of people, and would be more consistent with the regulations in place for other potentially addictive products such as alcohol and tobacco. Though policy-makers may fear a reduction in revenue if marketing is scaled back, diverting consumers’ spending away from gambling and toward more sustainable industries (or toward their own savings) may make for a more resilient economy in the long term. However, increased funding for problem gambling is unlikely to lead to major reductions in gambling harm unless policy-makers also implement meaningful restrictions on the supply of gambling, especially more harmful formats like EGMs.

We do not claim that any of these reforms will be easy. The gambling industry—and provincial treasuries’ addiction to its profits—is a multi-billion-dollar affair, and withdrawal will inevitably involve some short-term pain. Yet given the significant issues of justice—economic, political, social, and moral—at stake, we believe that the rewards of getting clean are well worth it.

                                See the Policy Brief - Turning Aces into Assets here